Summary
More than a decade after the outbreak of the global financial crisis in summer 2007, financial-market participants and central banks are asking what policy options are left. How much leeway do central banks have to cut interest rates again, to revive the economy in the event of a recession and to stabilise inflation expectations? Could central banks resume their bond purchases? What other options are on the table, both theoretically and in practice? It is implicitly assumed that the main task of central banks is to control the economic cycle, that an increase in stimulus also means an increase in growth and, consequently, that the benefits of monetary easing always outweigh the costs. Is this really true? Are these assumptions entirely valid? What other policy instruments are available besides monetary policy? What would be the right policy mix in the current environment? There is also the question of whether demand stimulation is necessary at all. We address all of these questions below.
Update Magazin II/2019 |
1 Monetary policy instruments
As a general rule, the monetary policy options currently
available (in theory) can be divided into two categories: on
the one hand, the use of conventional or unconventional
instruments; on the other hand, changing or adjusting
monetary-policy objectives.
The scope for using conventional monetary-policy
instruments is clearly limited at the present time. This also
applies to the Federal Reserve – which, admittedly, raised
the fed funds target rate in nine steps since the end of 2015
to a range of 2.25% to 2.5%, before cutting the rate again by 25bp at the 30–31 July meeting of the Federal Open Market Committee. However,
this rate is still low by historical standards, and below what
we estimate to be the “neutral” level. Yet before, during and
after past recessions, the Fed needed to – and was able to
– reduce the key interest rate by considerably more (around
5%) in order to revive economic growth. The situation is
different in Europe and Asia: in the euro zone, the main
refinancing rate stands at 0%, while the UK base rate is just
a little higher at 0.75%. Of course, central banks can cut their
interest rates to below 0% – as seen, for example, in Japan
(–0.10% or –10 bp), Switzerland (–75 bp) or Sweden (–25 bp
today, but –50 bp between 2016 and 2018). However,
there is an “effective lower bound”, which is currently
estimated at around –1% to –1.5%. If interest rates fall
below this effective floor, private individuals and
companies withdraw money from their accounts and
hold large amounts of cash.
In other words, if a recession occurs in the major
industrialised countries, conventional interest rate cuts are
de facto only available as a monetary-policy instrument in
the US – and even there only to a limited extent.
As a second conventional instrument, central banks could
carry on making large – or even unlimited – amounts of
liquidity available to the banking sector. Another option,
albeit an unconventional one, is to offer cheap liquidity to
the financial sector over the longer term, perhaps linked
to lending to the private sector. This is being done by the
European Central Bank (ECB) – which, starting in
September, will offer two repos to banks with a maturity of
two years as part of the “TLTRO 3” (targeted longer-term
refinancing operations) programme. These will be offered
at an attractive interest rate up to 30 bp below the general
repo rate, provided banks expand their loan portfolios.
However, it is doubtful whether this measure will succeed.
Banks are already “swimming” in surplus liquidity – not
just in the euro zone, but worldwide. They don’t need this
liquidity injection.
Can and should central banks revert to the unconventional
instrument of asset purchases that was eventually used by all
the major central banks in the wake of the financial crisis?
This would of course be possible in theory, but there are
institutional, legal and monetary-policy limitations. On the
one hand, this is because purchase programmes by priceinsensitive
central banks run the risk of drying up liquidity
in the markets. This is true not only of less liquid market
segments such as corporate bonds. In Japan, trade in
Japanese government bonds has even come to a standstill
several times in recent years – and no wonder: the Bank of
Japan (BoJ) now holds significantly more than 40% of all
outstanding Japanese government bonds. The ECB also
comes up against a legal problem. Admittedly, the European
Court of Justice did not impose a ceiling on purchases of
government bonds, and regarded previous purchases as an
instrument of monetary policy. But at the same time it clearly
stressed that unlimited purchases of government bonds are
not allowed, as it would be illegal for the ECB to finance
budget deficits. Could central banks also buy equities?
The BoJ is already doing this in the form of purchases of
exchange-traded funds. Although there are legal concerns
for the ECB and the Fed, the consensus is that the legal
hurdles are not insurmountable. Rather, monetary policy and
practical considerations may prevent the Fed and the ECB
from using this instrument. It is doubtful whether purchases
of equities would really have the desired “portfolio-balance
effect”. This means that financial-market participants invest
in increasingly risky assets, and ultimately stimulate credit
growth, because the expected returns on less risky assets
have become unattractive due to asset purchases by the
central bank. However, equities are already a risky asset
class, and the effect would probably be much smaller than
buying government bonds. Corporate-governance
considerations – the question of whether a central bank as
a shareholder should have a direct or indirect influence on
corporate decisions – is another reason why we think it
unlikely that equities will become part of an asset-purchase
program, or that the corporate-bond purchase program will
be expanded significantly. Including bonds issued by banks
in the asset-purchase program, too, is difficult to conceive: as
central banks are involved in supervising banks, a conflict of
interest might arise.1
An extreme form of liquidity provision would be the use of
“helicopter money”. This involves central banks injecting
massive amounts of liquidity directly into government coffers
or private households. Indeed, it has been and continues to
be advocated by economists, including Ben Bernanke, as a
solution to Japan’s low nominal growth. However, most
economists reject this idea because it would seriously
jeopardise confidence in the monetary system.
Another unconventional policy option that has been
used for years is “forward guidance” – that is to say,
communication by central banks about the future level of
interest rates. This instrument is unlimited both in theory
and in practice, since central banks can extend the time
window for which they give a commitment for as long
as they want. (On the other hand, tying interest rates
to the trend of economic variables, such as the rate of
unemployment, encounters limits sooner or later.)
Ultimately, the effectiveness of the forward guidance
depends on how credibly the central bank commits to its
own targets.
A/ Global key central bank rates
Source: Refinitv-Datastream
Past performance is not a reliable indicator of future returns.
2 Redefining policy objectives
Beyond the use of monetary-policy instruments, central
banks could also readjust their monetary-policy objectives.
The Fed is in fact reviewing its monetary-policy strategy
until the end of 2019, with the eventual aim of anchoring
long-term inflation expectations.
Options include setting a multi-year average inflation goal
or aiming for a price-index target. This means that if the
inflation target is temporarily undershot, an overshoot will
be allowed in the future. But this is precisely the problem
with these “make-up strategies”: as noted in academic
literature, they are generally “time-inconsistent”. Their
success depends on the private sector having confidence
that the strategy will be implemented, even if inflation
exceeds the target. Moreover, it is also unclear from an ex
ante perspective whether the mere announcement of a
changed definition of the inflation target will influence the
expectations of companies and households.
Another option would be simply to raise the inflation
target. Here, too, the question is how credibly this can be
communicated and, moreover, whether a higher inflation
target of, say, 4% would be at all desirable. Current
prevailing doctrine puts the ideal rate of inflation for
developed industrialised countries at 2%.
Over the medium to longer term, there is a risk that an excessively expansionary monetary policy will also lead to a misallocation of resources, and an increase in financial-stability risks.
3 The costs of further monetary stimulus
Goods-price inflation in almost all countries has been below
the central banks’ long-term target for years, and this has
created a tendency to ignore the costs of permanent
monetary stimulus. Indeed, in the public debate over the
need for further monetary stimulus, the adverse side-effects
of expansionary monetary policy are usually neglected.
Besides the aforementioned problem of the “zero lower
bound” – ie, the lower limit of interest rates, which is the
reason why central banks have resorted to unconventional
measures in the past – an extremely loose monetary policy
has further drawbacks, especially when adopted over a
prolonged period.
For example, it is difficult for the banking system to pass
negative interest rates to private households: the deposit
rate for private individuals is de facto “underpinned” on the
downside at 0%. Lending rates are reduced along with the
general level of interest rates, thereby shrinking banks’
interest margins and profit potential. Yet profits are the
most important way for banks to generate equity capital.
A prolonged period of negative interest rates thereby runs
the risk of jeopardising the stability of the banking sector,
and limiting growth opportunities for the economy. Pension
funds and insurance companies are also suffering from
the low-interest-rate environment, as the present value of
obligations rises with declining yields.
Over the medium to longer term, there is a risk that an
excessively expansionary monetary policy will also lead to
a misallocation of resources and an increase in financialstability
risks: if interest rates stay below the “neutral” level
for long, investors will become more willing to take risks, and
private-sector debt will increase. It also becomes possible to
finance less productive projects, since the price of capital is
artificially low. Real estate booms and bubbles are the best
examples of this. Indeed, we note that the private-sector
debt ratio (companies and households) climbed last year to
a record level of around 150% of global GDP. At the same
time, real-estate prices again rose sharply worldwide.
In the United States in particular, corporate-sector debt has
reached new highs, while the quality of debt instruments
has fallen significantly – as shown by the historically high
proportion of bonds rated BBB. The rise in leveraged loans
– ie, loans to highly indebted companies – is a particular
cause for concern. Companies can of course continue to
service even high levels of debt, as long as interest rates stay
low and growth remains steady. But this is no argument
for complacency: when the economy slows down, debt
sustainability usually deteriorates quite quickly.
Would macroprudential measures (such as countercyclical
capital buffers for banks) be a suitable way to curb growing
risks to financial stability? They undoubtedly make sense
as supporting measures. However, there is still insufficient
empirical data to determine how much regulatory
counteraction is necessary. It is also difficult to see why
monetary policy should seek to stimulate credit growth
while, at the same time, regulation aims to achieve precisely
the opposite.
Rising debt in the private sector can also have other
consequences. Studies by the Bank for International
Settlements and Organisation for Economic Co-operation
and Development have demonstrated the structural
increase in the proportion of companies with low
productivity and high debt – so-called “zombie companies” –
in recent decades. This is due to the phenomenon of
“evergreening” loans – that is to say, the renewal of bank
loans even for weaker companies. The low-interest-rate
environment has clearly favoured this trend. The low
productivity growth observed over many years can
therefore be explained, at least in part, by expansionary
monetary policy.
Against this background, it would make more sense in the
long run to normalise monetary policy – ie, to raise interest
rates to a neutral level – rather than to continue or expand
monetary-policy stimulation.
4 The need for fiscal stimulus
Since the use of monetary-policy instruments is limited for
various reasons – in addition, their effectiveness is clearly
limited in the current environment, and adverse side effects
also have to be taken into account – fiscal policy should play
a greater role in demand management.
This is especially true in the current global economic slowdown
caused by factors such as the US-China trade war and Brexit.
Both factors increase business uncertainty, depress sentiment
and consequently dampen investment activity worldwide.
If the current weakness of aggregate demand leads to a
recession, it would be appropriate to implement governmentspending
programs and tax cuts, rather than just relying on
“automatic stabilisers”. This is particularly true for countries
with fiscal policy leeway – ie, with moderate public debt and
low budget deficits (or even budget surpluses). The only
problem is that many industrialised countries have limited
fiscal-policy scope – public debt in industrialised countries
averages around 120% of GDP. Empirical studies show that
high public debt can cause lower potential growth in the long
term. In Europe, moreover, deficit ceilings also limit most
countries’ ability to use fiscal-stimulus programmes.
Advocates of “modern monetary theory” (MMT) see no
problem with this. They argue that fiscal leeway is ultimately
inexhaustible, as the central bank, being a public institution,
can buy an unlimited volume of government bonds. However,
MMT ignores the fact that such a policy undermines long-term
confidence in the currency.
5 Structural policy is imperative
Both monetary and fiscal policy can address weaknesses in overall economic demand. But they are not a way to increase the productivity of an economy; in the worst case they are literally counterproductive, as explained above. Structural reforms, an efficient competition policy, financial support for start-ups, smart investment in education and, in particular, greater openness to international markets can all help to boost overall productivity.
Empirical studies show that high public debt can cause lower potential growth in the long term.
B/ Global government debt
Sources: AllianzGI, Refinitiv-Datastream, BIS, Data as at 2018.
Past performance is not a reliable indicator of future returns.
6 Implications for investors
At the end of January, the Fed took us and the markets by surprise by hinting at a relaxation of monetary policy. The market is now even discounting interest-rate cuts of 100 bp by the end of 2020. The Fed itself speaks of possible interest-rate cuts as a preventive measure (an “insurance rate cut”) to guard against recession. Other central banks have followed suit. The ECB will launch a new long-term tender (TLTRO 3) in September, and members of the ECB’s governing council have also raised expectations of interest-rate cuts and bond purchases in the near future. In addition, the Bank of England’s (BoE) recent communications have been “dovish”. Equity markets greeted this actual or anticipated monetarypolicy stimulus with price gains. Will this remain the case in the future? Here are some points to bear in mind2:
- The prices of risky assets usually react positively to a loosening of monetary policy if economic data improve at the same time. However, this year the data flow has been fairly weak throughout the world. Our leading indicators that look two to four quarters ahead also point to a somewhat difficult growth environment going forward. US recession risks in 2020 are mounting.
- The relationship between easy monetary policy and equity prices is less clear-cut than one might think. Major setbacks frequently occur even in periods of low interest rates. They can be triggered by growth concerns (eg, in 2015/16, even though there was no recession) or by high valuations (eg, in 2007/08). We think that US equities are currently ambitiously valued.
- There is still leeway for monetary policy in general terms, but less than there was before the financial crisis. Moreover, the effectiveness of monetary policy is limited in the current environment.
- Monetary-loosening measures may possibly extend the current cycle. More than a decade of loose monetary policy also means higher risks to financial-market stability. The rising private-sector debt levels are a case in point.
- Fiscal stimulus measures could relieve pressure on monetary policy in the event of a recession. At present, however, there are few signs of global and coordinated fiscal relaxation. The longer-term growth outlook is strongly dependent on a successful structural policy with a positive impact on productivity growth.
From our perspective, this means that many factors
besides changes in monetary policy are relevant when it
comes to making portfolio decisions – especially for us as
an active asset manager.
C/ Policy options
Source: AllianzGI. For illustrative purposes only
Equity markets greeted this actual or anticipated monetary-policy stimulus with price gains. Will this remain the case in the future?
1) The statements contained herein may include forecasts or expectations or other forward-looking
statements and may involve known and unknown risks and uncertainties. Actual results and performance may
differ materially from those expressed or implied in such forward-looking statements. We assume no obligation
to update any forward-looking statement.
2) The statements contained herein may include forecasts or expectations or other forward-looking
statements
and may involve known and unknown risks and uncertainties. Actual results and performance may
differ
materially from those expressed or implied in such forward-looking statements. We assume no obligation
to update any forward-looking statement.
Investing involves risk. The statements contained herein may include statements of future
expectations and other forward-looking statements that are based on management‘s current
views and assumptions and involve known and unknown risks and uncertainties that could
cause actual results, performance or events to differ materially from those expressed or implied
in such statements. We assume no obligation to update any forward-looking statement. The
value of an investment and the income from it may fall as well as rise and investors may not get
back the full amount invested. There is no guarantee that the strategy will succeed and losses
cannot be ruled out. Investors may not get back the full amount invested.
The volatility of fund unit prices may be increased or even strongly increased. Past
performance is not a reliable indicator of future results. If the currency in which the past
performance is displayed differs from the currency of the country in which the investor resides,
then the investor should be aware that due to the exchange rate fluctuations the performance
shown may be higher or lower if converted into the investor’s local currency.
This is for information only and not to be construed as a solicitation or an invitation to make an
offer, to conclude a contract, or to buy or sell any securities. The products or securities described
herein may not be available for sale in all jurisdictions or to certain categories of investors.
This is for distribution only as permitted by applicable law and in particular not available to
residents and/or nationals of the USA. The investment opportunities described herein do not
take into account the specific investment objectives, financial situation, knowledge, experience
or particular needs of any particular person and are not guaranteed. The views and opinions
expressed herein, which are subject to change without notice, are those of the issuer and/or its
affiliated companies at the time of publication. The data used is derived from various sources,
and assumed to be correct and reliable, but it has not been independently verified; its accuracy
or completeness is not guaranteed and no liability is assumed for any direct or consequential
losses arising from its use, unless caused by gross negligence or willful misconduct. The
conditions of any underlying offer or contract that may have been, or will be, made or
concluded, shall prevail.
Contact the issuer electronically or via mail at the address indicated below for a free copy of
the sales prospectus, the incorporation documents, the latest annual and semi-annual financial
reports and the key investor information document in English. Please read these documents –
which are solely binding – carefully before investing.
For investors in Europe (excluding Switzerland): This is a marketing communication issued
by Allianz Global Investors GmbH, www.allianzgi.com, an investment company with limited
liability, incorporated in Germany, with its registered office at Bockenheimer Landstrasse 42–44,
60323 Frankfurt/M, registered with the local court Frankfurt/M under HRB 9340, authorised by
Bundesanstalt für Finanzdienstleistungsaufsicht (www.bafin.de). Allianz Global Investors GmbH
has established branches in the United Kingdom, France, Italy, Spain, Luxembourg and the
Netherlands. Contact details and information on the local regulation are available here
(www.allianzgi.com/Info).
For investors in Switzerland: This is a marketing communication issued by Allianz Global Investors
(Schweiz) AG, a 100% subsidiary of Allianz Global Investors GmbH, licensed by FINMA
(www.finma.ch) for distribution and by OAKBV (Oberaufsichtskommission berufliche Vorsorge)
for asset management related to occupational pensions.. Details about the extent of the local
regulation are available from us on request.
This report does not satisfy all legal requirements on the guarantee of impartiality in investment
recommendations and investment strategy recommendations and is not subject to any trade
restrictions prior to the publication of such recommendations. The duplication, publication, or
transmission of the contents, irrespective of the form, is not permitted.
Summary
What does it mean to be a long-term investor? That was one of the main questions underpinning the discussions at our Investment Forum in Frankfurt. Topics included the importance of climate change and the future direction of Europe, as our investors and strategists shaped the convictions that inform our long-term investment strategies for clients.